IFFM Blog #5 Capital Structure: Theory, Research and Practice
In the previous post, it was discussed that a company that is hoping to gain investors should first evaluate their cost of capital in order to ensure that cash generated is sufficient to cover the rate of returns expected by investors, as well as for company growth. This is calculated primarily through the use of Weighted Average Cost of Capital (WACC) formula should a firm have a mixed Capital Structure. According to Murray, capital structure is defined as the combination of equity and debt that a firm has on its balance sheets (Murray, 2017). Companies strive to optimise their WACC such that it is most beneficial for their operations. While individuals ranging from academics to corporate management have hypothesised the ideal capital structure models, the theories on what works best is not reflected in successful companies around the world (Baker, Singleton and Veit, 2010) One factor that results in this is that how persons managing a company decide to structure the firm's debt or equity differs across the board based on their agendas.
The notion of capital structure was first coherently explained by Modigliani and Miller in a paper published in 1958 (Modigliani & Miller, 1958). Modigliani and Miller's Theory of Capital Structure presents that the valuation of a firm is not relevant to its capital structure. Instead, the profits made from operations is what drives the valuation. The conditions that had to be met in their theory include no taxes, no costs of financial burden, that all agents have access to the same information, and that firms can be classified according to risk classes (MM Propositions I and II (Case with No Taxes), 2018) While it is important to understand this theory, some assumptions that were made by the duo renders the idea inapplicable to reality (Ozyasar, n.d.). The assumptions were:
- There are no transaction costs.
- Businesses and investors are able to borrow at the same cost.
- If there are worthwhile investment opportunities, the company will pursue them. If not, the company will return excess cash to shareholders in dividends.
In reality, there certainly are transaction costs in business dealings. For instance, companies that run e-commerce websites pay a transaction fee to services such as Braintree, which aids in facilitating the customer payment process. Businesses and investors as individuals borrow at different costs, and companies do not always instantly move excess cash generated from operations. Nevertheless, Modigliani and Miller's journal article earned them a Nobel prize (Modigliani, 1985).
It also paved the way for other theories such as the Trade-Off Models of Capital Structure, which states that companies strive for a "value-maximising optimal capital structure" that greatly reduces the WACC (Kraus and Litzenberger, 1973) According to Trade-Off Models, company valuation is independent of capital structure, and gearing is able to increase the wealth of investors/shareholders only up to a certain point. Gearing refers to a firm's leverage (Peavler, 2018) In other words, gearing is the amount of funding that originates from creditors as opposed to people who own the company (Peavler, 2018).
References
Murray, J. (2017). 3 Definitions of Business Capital. [online] The Balance. Available at: https://www.thebalance.com/capital-and-capital-structure-of-a-business-398170 [Accessed 1 Feb. 2018].
Baker, H., Singleton, J. and Veit, E. (2010). Survey research in corporate finance. Oxford Scholarship Online.
Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. (1958). The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment. The American Economic Review, 48(3), 261-297. Retrieved from http://www.jstor.org/stable/1809766
MM Propositions I and II (Case with No Taxes). (2018). [ebook] Available at: http://finance.wharton.upenn.edu/~jwachter/fnce100/h13.pdf [Accessed 1 Feb. 2018].
Ozyasar, H. (n.d.). Assumptions of the Modigliani-Miller Theorem. [online] Smallbusiness.chron.com. Available at: http://smallbusiness.chron.com/assumptions-modiglianimiller-theorem-55674.html [Accessed 1 Feb. 2018].
Modigliani, F. (1985). The Prize in Economics 1985 - Press Release. [online] Nobelprize.org. Available at: https://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/1985/press.html [Accessed 1 Feb. 2018].
Kraus, A. and Litzenberger, R. (1973). A State-Preference Model of Optimal Financial Leverage. The Journal of Finance, 28(4), p.911.
Peavler, R. (2018). What High Gearing Ratios Say About a Company. [online] The Balance. Available at: https://www.thebalance.com/calculating-gearing-ratio-393228 [Accessed 1 Feb. 2018].
Comments
Post a Comment